You may only read this site if you've purchased Our Kampf from Amazon or Powell's or me
• • •
"Mike and Jon, Jon and Mike—I've known them both for years, and, clearly, one of them is very funny. As for the other: truly one of the great hangers-on of our time."—Steve Bodow, head writer, The Daily Show

"Who can really judge what's funny? If humor is a subjective medium, then can there be something that is really and truly hilarious? Me. This book."—Daniel Handler, author, Adverbs, and personal representative of Lemony Snicket

"The good news: I thought Our Kampf was consistently hilarious. The bad news: I’m the guy who wrote Monkeybone."—Sam Hamm, screenwriter, Batman, Batman Returns, and Homecoming

November 03, 2008

H.L. Mencken Explains Economists

To the credit of Robert Shiller, an economics professor at Stutts, he warned for years of the housing bubble and its likely consequences. However, based on his New York Times op-ed yesterday, he still struggles with perceiving the obvious elsewhere:

Why do professional economists always seem to find that concerns with bubbles are overblown or unsubstantiated? I have wondered about this for years, and still do not quite have an answer.

Everything worth saying about this was said almost ninety years ago, in H.L. Mencken's famous essay "The Dismal Science":

[T]o what extent is political economy, as professors expound and practice it, a free science, in the sense that mathematics and physiology are free sciences?...

Their colleagues of archeology may be reasonably called free, and their colleagues of bacteriology, and those of Latin grammar and sidereal astronomy, and those of many another science and mystery, but when one comes to the faculty of political economy one finds that freedom as plainly conditioned, though perhaps not as openly, as in the faculty of theology. And for a plain reason. Political economy, so to speak, hits the employers of the professors where they live. It deals, not with ideas that affect those employers only occasionally or only indirectly or only as ideas, but with ideas that have an imminent and continuous influence upon their personal welfare and security, and that affect profoundly the very foundations of that social and economic structure upon which their whole existence is based. It is, in brief, the science of the ways and means whereby they have come to such estate, and maintain themselves in such estate, that they are able to hire and boss professors...

One remembers, for example, the trial, condemnation and execution of Prof. Dr. Scott Nearing at the University of Pennsylvania...Nearing was not thrown out of the University of Pennsylvania, angrily and ignominiously, because he was honestly wrong, or because his errors made him incompetent to prepare sophomores for their examinations; he was thrown out because his efforts to get at the truth disturbed the security and equanimity of the rich ignoranti who happened to control the university...he was thrown out because he was not safe and sane and orthodox. Had his aberration gone in the other direction, had he defended child labor as ardently as he denounced it and denounced the minimum wage as ardently as he defended it, then he would have been quite secure in his post...

Now consider the case of the professors of economics, near and far, who have not been thrown out. Who will say that the lesson of the Nearing débêcle has been lost upon them? Who will say that the potency of the wealthy men who command our universities—or most of them—has not stuck in their minds?...It seems to me that these considerations are enough to cast a glow of suspicion over the whole of American political economy...over practically every one of them there stands a board of trustees with its legs in the stock-market and its eyes on the established order, and that board is ever alert for heresy in the science of its being, and has ready means of punishing it, and a hearty enthusiasm for the business...every last pedagogue must be well aware of it.

An interesting thing about Stutts is that professors, in order to mingle successfully at parties, must simultaneously (1) have enough cultural literacy to know who social critics like H.L. Mencken were, and (2) never read anything by them.

The text of the essay doesn't seem to be online anywhere. So to assist Google, I'll put the whole thing below the fold.

"The Dismal Science"
by H.L. Mencken

EVERY man, as the Psalmist says, to his own poison, or poisons, as the case may be. One of mine, following hard after theology, is political economy. What! Political economy, that dismal science? Well, why not? Its dismalness is largely a delusion, due to the fact that its chief ornaments, at least in our own day, are university professors. The professor must be an obscurantist or he is nothing; he has a special and unmatchable talent for dullness; his central aim is not to expose the truth clearly, but to exhibit his profundity, his esotericity—in brief, to stagger sophomores and other professors. The notion that German is a gnarled and unintelligible language arises out of the circumstance that it is so much written by professors. It took a rebel member of the clan, swinging to the antipodes in his unearthly treason, to prove its explicitness, its resiliency, it downright beauty. But Nietzsches are few, and so German remains soggy, and political economy continues to be swathed in dullness. As I say, however, that dullness is only superficial. There is no more engrossing book in the English language than Adam Smith's "The Wealth of Nations"; surely the eighteenth century produced nothing that can be read with greater ease to-day. Nor is there any inherent reason why even the most technical divisions of its subject should have gathered cobwebs with the passing of the years. Taxation, for example, is eternally lively; it concerns nine-tenths of us more directly than either smallpox or golf, and has just as much drama in it; moreover, it has been mellowed and made gay by as many gaudy, preposterous theories. As for foreign ex change, it is almost as romantic as young love, and quite as resistent to formulæ. Do the professors make an autopsy of it? Then read the occasional treatises of some professor of it who is not a professor, say, Garet Garrett or John Moody.

Unluckily, Garretts and Moodys are almost as rare as Nietzsches, and so the amateur of such things must be content to wrestle with the professors, seeking the violet of human interest beneath the avalanche of their graceless parts of speech. A hard business, I daresay, to one not practiced, and to its hardness there is added the disquiet of a doubt. That doubt does not concern itself with the doctrine preached, at least not directly. There may be in it nothing intrinsically dubious; on the contrary, it may appear as sound as the binomial theorem, as well supported as the dogma of infant damnation. But all the time a troubling question keeps afloat in the air, and that is briefly this: What would happen to the learned professors if they took the other side? In other words, to what extent is political economy, as professors expound and practice it, a free science, in the sense that mathematics and physiology are free sciences? At what place, if any, is speculation pulled up by a rule that beyond lies treason, anarchy and disaster? These questions, I hope I need not add, are not inspired by any heterodoxy in my own black heart. I am, in many fields, a flouter of the accepted revelation and hence immoral, but the field of economics is not one of them. Here, indeed, I know of no man who is more orthodox than I am. I believe that the present organization of society, as bad as it is, is better than any other that has ever been proposed. I reject all the sure cures in current agitation, from government ownership to the single tax. I am in favor of free competition in all human enterprises, and to the utmost limit. I admire successful scoundrels, and shrink from Socialists as I shrink from Methodists. But all the same, the afore said doubt pursues me when I plow through the solemn disproofs and expositions of the learned professors of economics, and that doubt will not down. It is not logical or evidential, but purely psycho logical. And what it is grounded on is an unshakable belief that no man's opinion is worth a hoot, however well supported and maintained, so long as he is not absolutely free, if the spirit moves him, to support and maintain the exactly contrary opinion. In brief, human reason is a weak and paltry thing so long as it is not wholly free reason. The fact lies in its very nature, and is revealed by its entire history. A man may be perfectly honest in a contention, and he may be astute and persuasive in maintaining it, but the moment the slightest compulsion to maintain it is laid upon him, the moment the slightest external re ward goes with his partisanship or the slightest penalty with its abandonment, then' there appears a defect in his ratiocination that is more deep-seated than any error in fact and more destructive than any conscious and deliberate bias. He may seek the truth and the truth only, and bring up his highest talents and diligence to the business, but always there is a specter behind his chair, a warning in his ear. Always it is safer and more hygienic for him to think one way than to think another way, and in that bald fact there is excuse enough to hold his whole chain of syllogisms in suspicion. He may be earnest, he may be honest, but he is not free, and if he is not free, he is not anything.

Well, are the reverend professors of economics free? With the highest respect, I presume to question it. Their colleagues of archeology may be reasonably called free, and their colleagues of bacteriology, and those of Latin grammar and sidereal astronomy, and those of many another science and mystery, but when one comes to the faculty of political economy one finds that freedom as plainly conditioned, though perhaps not as openly, as in the faculty of theology. And for a plain reason. Political economy, so to speak, hits the employers of the professors where they live. It deals, not with ideas that affect those employers only occasionally or only indirectly or only as ideas, but with ideas that have an imminent and continuous influence upon their personal welfare and security, and that affect profoundly the very foundations of that social and economic structure upon which their whole existence is based. It is, in brief, the science of the ways and means whereby they have come to such estate, and maintain themselves in such estate, that they are able to hire and boss professors. It is the boat in which they sail down perilous waters—and they must needs yell, or be more or less than human, when it is rocked. Now and then that yell duly resounds in the groves of learning. One remembers, for example, the trial, condemnation and execution of Prof. Dr. Scott Nearing at the University of Pennsyl vania, a seminary that is highly typical, both in its staff and in its control. Nearing, I have no doubt, was wrong in his notions—honestly, perhaps, but still wrong. In so far as I heard them stated at the time, they seemed to me to be hollow and of no validity. He has since discharged them from the chautauquan stump, and at the usual hinds. They have been chiefly accepted and celebrated by men I regard as asses. But Nearing was not thrown out of the University of Pennsylvania, angrily and ignominiously, because he was honestly wrong, or because his errors made him incompetent to prepare sophomores for their examinations; he was thrown out because his efforts to get at the truth disturbed the security and equanimity of the rich ignoranti who happened to control the university, and because the academic slaves and satellites of these shopmen were restive under his competition for the attention of the student-body. In three words, he was thrown out because he was not safe and sane and orthodox. Had his aberration gone in the other direction, had he defended child labor as ardently as he denounced it and denounced the minimum wage as ardently as he defended it, then he would have been quite as secure in his post, for all his cavorting in the newspapers, as Chancellor Day was at Syracuse.

Now consider the case of the professors of economics, near and far, who have not been thrown out. Who will say that the lesson of the Nearing débêcle has been lost upon them? Who will say that the potency of the wealthy men who command our universities—or most of them—has not stuck in their minds? And who will say that, with this sticking remembered, their arguments against Nearing's so-called ideas are as worthy of confidence and respect as they would be if they were quite free to go over to Nearing's side without damage? Who, indeed, will give them full credit, even when they are right, so long as they are hamstrung, nose-ringed and tied up in gilded pens? It seems to me that these considerations are enough to cast a glow of suspicion over the whole of American political economy, at least in so far as it comes from college economists. And, in the main, it has that source, for, barring a few brilliant journalists, all our economists of any repute are professors. Many of them are able men, and most of them are undoubtedly honest men, as honesty goes in the world, but over practically every one of them there stands a board of trustees with its legs in the stock-market and its eyes on the established order, and that board is ever alert for heresy in the science of its being, and has ready means of punish ing it, and a hearty enthusiasm for the business. Not every professor, perhaps, may be sent straight to the block, as Nearing was, but there are plenty of pillories and guardhouses on the way, and every last pedagogue must be well aware of it.

Political economy, in so far as it is a science at all, was not pumped up and embellished by any such academic clients and ticket-of-leave men. It was put on its legs by inquirers who were not only safe from all dousing in the campus pump, but who were also free from the mental timorousness and conformity which go inevitably with school-teaching—in brief, by men of the world, accustomed to its free air, its hospitality to originality and plain speaking. Adam Smith, true enough, was once a professor, but he threw up his chair to go to Paris, and there he met, not more professors, but all the current enemies of professors—the Nearings and Henry Georges and Karl Marxes of the time. And the book that he wrote was not orthodox, but revolutionary. Consider the others of that bulk and beam: Bentham, Ricardo, Mill and their like. Bentham held no post at the mercy of bankers and tripesellers; he was a man of independent means, a lawyer and politician, and a heretic in general practice. It is impossible to imagine such a man occupying a chair at Harvard or Princeton. He had a hand in too many pies: he was too rebellious and contumacious: he had too little respect for authority, either academic or worldly. Moreover, his mind was too wide for a professor; he could never remain safely in a groove; the whole field of social organization invited his inquiries and experiments. Ricardo? Another man of easy means and great worldly experience—by academic standards, not even educated. To-day, I daresay, such meager diplomas as he could show would not suffice to get him an instructor's berth in a freshwater seminary in Iowa. As for Mill, he was so well grounded by his father that he knew more, at eighteen, than any of the universities could teach him, and his life thereafter was the exact antithesis of that of a cloistered pedagogue. Moreover, he was a heretic in religion and probably violated the Mann act of those days—an offense almost as heinous, in a college professor of economics, as giving three cheers for Prince Kropotkin.

I might lengthen the list, but humanely refrain. The point is that these early English economists were all perfectly free men, with complete liberty to tell the truth as they saw it, regardless of its orthodoxy or lack of orthodoxy. I do not say that the typical American economist of to-day is not as honest, nor even that he is not as diligent and competent, but I do say that he is not as free—that penalties would come upon him for stating ideas that Smith or Ricard or Bentham or Mill, had he so desired, would have been free to state without damage. And in that menace there is an ineradicable criticism of the ideas that he does state, and it lingers even when they are plausible and are accepted. In France and Germany, where the universities and colleges are controlled by the state, the practical effect of such pressure has been frequently demonstrated. In the former country the violent debate over social and economic problems during the quarter century before the war produced a long list of professors cashiered for heterodoxy, headed by the names of Jean Jaures and Gustave Herve. In Germany it needed no Nietzsche to point out the deadening produced by this state control. Germany, in fact, got out of it an entirely new species of economist—the state Socialist who flirted with radicalism with one eye and kept the other upon his chair, his salary and his pension.

The Nearing case and the rebellions of various pedagogues elsewhere show that we in America stand within the shadow of a somewhat similar danger. In economics, as in the other sciences, we are probably producing men who are as good as those on view in any other country. They are not to be surpassed for learning and originality, and there is no reason to believe that they lack honesty and courage. But honesty and courage, as men go in the world, are after all merely relative values. There comes a point at which even the most honest man considers consequences, and even the most courageous looks before he leaps. The difficulty lies in establishing the position of that point. So long as it is in doubt, there will remain, too, the other doubt that I have described. I rise in meeting, I repeat, not as a radical, but as one of the most hunkerous of the orthodox. I can imagine nothing more dubious in fact and wobbly in logic than some of the doctrines that amateur economists, chiefly Socialists, have set afloat in this country during the past dozen years. I have even gone to the trouble of writing a book against them; my convictions and instincts are all on the other side. But I should be a great deal more comfortable in those convictions and instincts if I were convinced that the learned professors were really in full and absolute possession of academic freedom—if I could imagine them taking the other tack now and then without damnation to their jobs, their lecture dates, their book sales and their hides.

—Jonathan Schwarz

Posted at November 3, 2008 09:25 AM
Comments
...American political economy...

The hope here is that globalization is a two edged sword (or at least two edged).

It has the capacity to wane nationalistic gibberish and contaminate the American political economy with humane socialism that (obviously) works, as well as distribute pain trans nationally when caused by the hyper-class transnationalists. Plus, the information sharing provided by the intertubes can offset some of the negatives if global regulation actually takes place to do good -- such as global regulation in banking in finance that is focused on transparency for the sake of baselined humanity rather than what is currently done for the sake of political combating and de-funding "terrorism".

I don't know why I'd put terrorism in quotes there but I felt compelled to.

The Mencken piece is excellent. Can you run it through a GenY filter?

Posted by: Labiche at November 3, 2008 10:32 AM

Good piece but Mencken is so utterly confused about French academia. Not sure what happened to Gustave Herve, but the guy was a fascist, a great admirer of Mussolini. So if he had trouble with the French state, well, too bad.

Mencken's point about Jaures is ludicrous. Jaures always enjoyed the full support of university deans. The only time in his life he was denied a teaching assignment was at the U Paris when, as a socialist leader, he offered to teach about socialism. But his PhD thesis was on German socialism (he approved) and that got him a professorship.

In general, Mencken is so off-base about state-controlled academia. It's in French universities that you find (by far) the most rebellious, "freest" (in his sense) thinking in the country. In fact I cannot think of any anti-establishment movement in France in the 20c that didn't have its roots in academia, from the Dreyfus affair to the May 68 events. French academia is almost systematically opposed to the government. (Something very refreshing I no longer find in the US and have rarely found in the UK.)


Posted by: Bernard Chazelle at November 3, 2008 01:36 PM

I love this:

"An interesting thing about Stutts is that professors, in order to mingle successfully at parties, must simultaneously (1) have enough cultural literacy to know who social critics like H.L. Mencken were, and (2) never read anything by them."

I never would have believed it while I was there, but it explains SO MUCH. I came around to this view when I read Chomsky (no surprise). His specific example is Adam Smith's "invisible hand", and the ways in which the modern interpretation of that phrase has nothing to do with his meaning.

Posted by: Aaron Datesman at November 3, 2008 02:12 PM

To back up Menken, one need only look at who established the London School of Economics and the the University of Chicago (think Milton Friedman).
To further back up Menken, it is extraordinary the number of the economically trained who don't know how money comes into existence or, if they do, who does it.

Posted by: JamesS at November 3, 2008 04:18 PM

Perhaps the problem with (American) academia doesn't lie with the %1 of (American) 'pedagogues' who rock the boat or the (American) administrators who discipline them, but the %99 percent (of Americans) who queue up to the party line.

The %99 who let fear rule. (Numbers pulled from my imagination) Fear of any ideas out of the mainstream, or that threaten the precious status quo. I hate the term sheeple, but this is very sheeplike behavior. Perhaps admirable in sheep, but thoroughly repulsive in humans.

Labiche: Centralized national governments don't work well, so you advocate global centralization. My God, give the bankers the ability to regulate internationally and they won't even have nationalism to hold them back. Now that is something to be afraid of! Oh my, your post is going to give me nightmares of what 'baselined humanity' could mean over the evolution and devolution of a global system like yours.

Bernard: Shame about the French, really. I would say most of the highest ideals that our nation was created with were French in origin. The very concept of liberal politics itself, no? Such a shame to see charlatans on the Right use the term as an insult, and the Left's version of the same equate it to socialism.

Posted by: tim at November 3, 2008 06:51 PM
My God, give the bankers the ability to regulate internationally and they won't even have nationalism to hold them back.

Heh. Either I misstated or you misunderstood. I never intended to give the bankers the ability to regulate internationally. Instead, I advocated a collectivist utopia that's global, where the collectivist masses regulate.

See the difference?

Nut up dude; don't have nightmares over what baselined humanity means. It means something relatively simple like the UN convention on human rights where the same criteria on human dignity and freedom from molestation extends beyond nationalist borders.

See, unlike you, I don't have a lot of faith in nationalist solutions because I don't think that borders or laws that stop at borders fit real well in a closed ecosystem.

Posted by: Labiche at November 3, 2008 09:07 PM

All of this has actual biological roots: the most primitive part of the brain, the so called "reptilian brain" has embedded the three most basic instincts for humans:

Nourishment
Reproduction
Submission to the leader.

Yep, just that, submission is a basic human instinct. But unlike sex, nobody tells people they have to control it. Bless organized religion.

Posted by: Zanchito at November 4, 2008 02:49 AM

Reminds me of John Kenneth Galbraith from 1972:

"Economic instruction in the United States is about a hundred years old. In its first half century economists were subject to censorship by outsiders. Businessmen and their political and ideological acolytes kept watch on departments of economics and reacted promptly to heresy, the latter being anything that seemed to threaten the sanctity of property, profits, a proper tariff policy and a balanced budget, or that suggested sympathy for unions, public ownership, public regulation or, in any organised way, for the poor." (The Essential Galbraith, p. 135)

Not much has changed. And it does seem strange that few, if any, economists have studied how economic doctrine responds to supply and demand. Surely, if there is a demand for certain positions the marketplace of ideas will supply them? And, unsurprisingly, it does...

I would recommend Edward S. Herman's article "The Selling of Market Economics" (pp. 173-199, New Ways of Knowing, Marcus G. Raskin and Herbert J. Bernstein (eds.))

Posted by: Anarcho at November 4, 2008 03:52 AM

"an offense almost as heinous, in a college professor of economics, as giving three cheers for Prince Kropotkin."

I'm sure that Kropotkin, who rejected his position to become an anarchist, got really sick of people referring to him by his title... But, yes, three cheers for Kropotkin:

"Political Economy has always confined itself to stating facts occurring in society, and justifying them in the interest of the dominant class . . . Having found [something] profitable to capitalists, it has set it up as a principle." (The Conquest of Bread, p. 181)

Posted by: Anarcho at November 4, 2008 03:59 AM

Heh. Either I misstated or you misunderstood. I never intended to give the bankers the ability to regulate internationally. Instead, I advocated a collectivist utopia that's global, where the collectivist masses regulate.

See the difference?

No. This version might even be scarier. Just as an example of what collectivist masses regulate, see Prop. 8 in California. What happens when you don't like the outcome? For the record, I advocate a collectivist utopia too. I also realize that such a thing is not possible. You realize that too, right? Please tell me you do.


Nut up dude; don't have nightmares over what baselined humanity means. It means something relatively simple like the UN convention on human rights where the same criteria on human dignity and freedom from molestation extends beyond nationalist borders.

I won't have nightmares over what it means, only over what it could mean. Kind of like how the "final solution" sounds awesome when I'm taking a math test.. but not so great in other contexts. I meant the way that people can take phrases like that and turn them to their whims.

Posted by: tim at November 4, 2008 03:00 PM

Bernard - in the US, before the first world war, the anti-war left considered Herve an icon of anti-militarism (as it was called at the time) & also of anti-patriotism. See for example "Insurrection rather than war" (http://www.marxists.org/archive/herve/1906/insurrection.htm) I don't know when Herve made the transition from this to fascism but I think the picture that Mencken has in his mind of Herve is different from the picture you have.

Posted by: Erik at November 5, 2008 05:26 PM